Wednesday, February 9, 2011

Rain rain go away (from Sri Lanka) - Come again another day (in a mild way)

(February 09, 2011) Sri Lanka is severely affected by floods, landslides and other effects of climate change.

As the floods are yet to recede, the estimates of losses are being released by various sources of the government.

Sri Lanka government has roughly estimated that the floods have caused a damage worth of Rs. fifty billion to the economy while affecting people of 18 districts.

Minister of Disaster Management Mahinda Amaraweera says that thousands of acres of cultivations, around 450 small and big irrigation schemes, at least 75,000 cattle and many thousands of poultry and other animals were destroyed in floods.

Sri Lanka Minister of Peasants' Services and Wildlife S.M. Chandrasena says that 300,000 acres of paddy cultivations were completely destroyed due to recent floods.

Floods inundated 500,000 acres of paddy fields, damaged 458 big and small scale reservoirs, broke around 1000 irrigation canals and binds, the Minister stated.

Nine Peasants' Services Centers and seven fertilizer warehouses are also among the damaged property, he said.

Ampara, Batticaloa, Trincomalee, Anuradhapura, Polonnaruwa, Vavuniya, Kilinochchi and Mannar districts are the worst flood affected areas.

However, Minister of Agriculture Mahinda Yapa Abewardhana said to media that no scarcity of rice would be experienced by the country although floods hit the paddy cultivation hard. He said the country has buffer rice stocks for eight months. But the other government Ministers also contradict him and the rice mill owners have already rung the alarm by telling that they cannot supply rice at the government controlled prices due to the effects of the bad weather.

Meanwhile, the prices of vegetables has escalated to historical records in Sri Lanka. About 32 thousand hectares of vegetable cultivation have been destroyed due to the inclement weather says Secretary to the Ministry of Agriculture K.E. Karunathilaka.

Nearly 1.2 million people were affected by recent floods in Sri Lanka. Reports say the affected people are facing severe shortage of food commodities. Malnutrition will definitely follow the natural disasters.

One problem createsmore problems and the world is in a vicious circle of effects of climate change.

World has begun to pay the costs of capitalist plunder of nature in the past few centuries. After all, all the rhetoric of the scientific and technological advancements of the capitalism has gone to dead silence before the embarrassing helplessness of the system.

Asian Development Bank has launched a project to improve the understanding of climate-induced migration, and stimulate policy debate on how to tackle the anticipated movement of millions of people due to changing weather patterns in the coming years.

ADB says that the ultimate aim of this is to encourage the adoption of responsible, foresighted policies and practices that improve management of human displacement due to climate change, and where practical, enable communities to stay where they are.

It is interesting to examine why the ADB had to take the climate change as a serious issue. Densely populated Asia Pacific region of the world has become the most vulnerable area of the Earth. ADB says that 207 million people were affected world wide due to natural disaster and of them 87% are from Asia. South Asian countries like Pakistan, Bangladesh, India, Sri Lanka and Maldives are facing serious adverse effects of climate change. Rarely a day passes without reports on massive destruction caused by adverse effects of climate change.

The situation is no doubt the pay back of plunder of nature for two centuries  under capitalist production. The system has failed to prevent further plunder and to initiate remedial measures to heal ailing nature. The crisis proves that the human society needs a better production system than the present system that plunders man and nature to satisfy the greed of some.

-Ajith Perakum Jayasinghe


Monday, February 7, 2011

100,000 families landless in Mahaweli zones of Sri Lanka, says officials

(February 07, 2011) Sri Lanka government says that the farmers of the Mahaweli development areas are facing a severe shortage of land.

The Director General of the Mahaweli Authority D.M.C. Disanayaka said to Sinhala website Ethalaya that currently around 100,000 families of the Mahaweli zones are landless.

It is important the government assumed this in a time it is trying to grant thousands of acres of land for multi national companies to grow cash crops.

Recently, the government called the big businessmen to express interest to acquire state land for mass scale farming.


Sunday, February 6, 2011

Farmers across Asia support the Panama (Paanama) people to reclaim their lands

(February 06, 20110  About 190 farmer participants from the Philippines, Malaysia, Thailand, Bangladesh, Nepal, Pakistan, India, and Sri Lanka approved a resolution opposing the 'Land Grabbing' for the ‘Arugam Bay special tourism promotion zone’ and endorsed the struggles of the Panama (Paanama) peasantry to protect their lives, livelihoods and resources.


The news was broken by the Movement for Land and Agricultural Reform (MONLAR), who attended the 3rd general assembly of the Asian Peasant Coalition (APC) in Hanwella, Sri Lanka last January 23-24, 2011.

Comrade Sarath Fernando, the Convener of MONLAR, disclosed that members of the Asia-wide coalition had vowed to support the call of the peasantry of Panama to take back their lands and their struggle against the 'Arugam Bay Special Tourism Promotion Zone.'


“Farmers in the region under the banner of APC affirmed their international solidarity for MONLAR’s effort to better organize the 'resistance' of the peasantry in Panama and help them in every way possible to win their struggle especially in building their capacities in Agriculture and peasant economy”, added Sarath Fernando of MONLAR.

‘On January 24-25, 2011, fourteen (14) farmers/leaders from APC coming from Nepal, India, Pakistan and the Philippines joined members of MONLAR, VIKALPANI and National Farmers Assembly (NFA) for an exchange program at Panama, a peasant village in the South-East of Sri Lanka, situated at a distance of about 350 km from Colombo on the Eastern coast”, stated Fatima Burnad, APC Chairperson based in India.

The exchange program served as a venue where the Panama peasant community and the international participants were able to interact and learn from each other's experiences and successful stories.


“By now, 2,000 acres of community farm land had been completely blocked from entry in the 03 villages of SHASTHRAWELA, ULPASSA & RAGAMWELA in Panama West, now occupied by the military.…. Our plants were destroyed, our houses burnt! The Local Authorities and the Police are busy guarding the interests of the rich and the powerful who seek to grab these land plots through covert operation" remarked K. Kamal, a farmer who had lived off his land in Ragamwela for the past 25 years.


"I am a farther of six. We were never food insecure even in the hardest of times, since we grew our own food. But now, my children are starving, they don't want to study anymore! They are cordoning off my village, KURULU GAMMANAYA, nearly 1,000 acres of farmland. Further on, governmental agencies are now claiming ownership on top of our title deeds to around 2,000 acres of our crop land in HELAWA and PANAGALA. They want us to leave, to have 'development' in the form of 'tourism', and will eventually hand over these land plots to 'investors' to satisfy their greed for profits..…" warned H. Rooperathne, representing the Peasants Rights Protection & Development Foundation of Panama. Their sole cry..."We want our lands back!”


“The APC will continue to hold other international activities to promote the cause of Panama people and similar land issues in Asia. Therefore, the campaign to regain the lands of Panama people will be brought to international attention and will encourage solidarity of peasant organizations and people’s movements,” Burnad added.


“We call on President Mahinda Rajapaksa to act on Panama people’s appeal to reclaim their lands. Without lands there can be no life for them especially for their children. Finally, we call on the Panama people to continue their fight,” Burnad ended.

References: 
P. SOMASIRI,
Secretary, Panama Peasant Rights Protection & Development Foundation (Sri Lanka)
Contact No. +94-77-0761313
LAKPRIYA  NANAYAKKARA, Coordinator,  MONLAR (Sri Lanka)
Contact: +94-72-3404741, +94-11-2865534    Email: monlar@sltnet.lk
FATIMA BURNAD,  APC Chairperson (India)
Contact number: 42170702
Email: tnwforum@gmail.com


Wednesday, February 2, 2011

Sri Lanka's vegetable delivery techniques, waste and new laws

(February 02, 2011) Sri Lanka media reports that President Mahinda Rajapaksa has directed the officials to acquire 400,000 plastic crates to be released to the market so that the vegetable transporters can use them in safe delivery of vegetables.

The government has banned the use of gunny bags and other ad hoc packaging in delivery of vegetables and the use of crates has been made compulsory since February 01.

The authorities say that 20% of the harvest is wasted while being transported using improper delivery techniques. The aim of the move of the government is to prevent the waste of vegetable harvest while being transported to the markets. The government says that the waste of vegetable causes the increase of prices at the market.

However, some vegetable traders say that the trucks loaded with plastic crates can transport less weight of vegetables and the prices will further escalate with the making of using plastic crates compulsory in vegetable delivery.

They show the need of especially manufactured crates to transport different kinds of vegetables. The daily need of crates for the vegetable traders is 150,000, says the traders’ organization. However, the government failed to guarantee the supplies of crates before the ban on gunny bags was imposed.
Yesterday, the vegetable traders of Nuwaraeliya Economic Center boycotted supply of vegetables to Colombo in protest of the government action.


Monday, January 24, 2011

Lessons of the recent floods

By Sarath Fernando

What lessons can we learn from the recent floods in Sri Lanka? Severe damage has been caused to agriculture and land in over 11 districts. Over a million people have been affected. Many houses have come down; many earth slips have killed many people. The heavy rains came at the time when paddy was flowering and the crop losses would be very heavy. Reduced yields would lead to very high increase in food prices and would create food shortages. The international situation is not helpful either and dependence on imports is risky. Price increases in the essential foods have been serious already and further increases would be unbearable. It is reported that loss of cattle due to floods and extra ordinary cold has been very severe too. Already there are demands from companies to further increase imported milk powder prices.
It may be possible to blame nature for all these but it does not solve the problems. Natural disasters have to be expected and with increased intensity due to global warming and climate change. Many more climate change calamities are to be expected. It is necessary to provide relief to those who cannot face this situation on their own. But relief alone is not enough, but we have to learn the lessons that need to be learnt. The disaster is not over, it is just beginning. Crop losses and food shortages are to come. Diseases caused by floods are likely to increase, many reservoirs have been damaged and broken, they need to be repaired. More water shortages are likely to take place. Much of the top soil would have got eroded and many rivers, streams and reservoirs would have got silted. Can we remedy these sufficiently rapidly to reduce the damage.
Will the Government have enough money to do this? Can we borrow more without further burdening people with unbearable debt. Are we going to learn the lesson that we should not be intensifying the risks of disasters by causing further damage in trying to accelerate economic growth?

Manmade additions to disaster

Clearing more forests for further expansion of monoculture plantations, whether it is sugar cane plantations, banana plantations, pineapple, tobacco or cut flower would further increase disaster risks or growing more maize for animal feed, building express highways for facilitating faster transport for investors, growing more tobacco plantations to meet the needs of companies is another damage that further increase erosion, loss of soil fertility and other environmental losses. If we borrow more money we will have to do more exports to repay the loans, we have to obey advice and dictate of lenders and do what they want to exploit nature's resources and people more intensely.

A Vicious Circle

So, this is a vicious circle. We decide to provide more facilities to investors to exploit our people and our nature more extensively. It makes people poorer and nature more susceptible to disasters. Then we borrow more and make the cost of living worse. So, we have to give more concessions to investors. To do this we have to drive away more people from their land, from beaches, from cities and from villages. Can we push the poorer people from their village lands and also poorer people from cities at the same time? Where are they going to live and how are they going to survive?

Created Disaster

We were advised to give people opportunities to sell their land in villages, give up their food production replacing it with growing more crops for export or for alcohol and agro fuel. We were told to encourage more people to sell away their little plots of land to allow land accumulation in the hands of rich businesses for production of export crops instead of domestic food at affordable cost. We were advised to allow more space and facilities and tax concessions to private businesses, asked to privatize water and allow water marketing, Told to push fisher people away from their beaches and fishing livelihoods to allow tourism to expand and big fishing industry to take over. There were attempts made to utilize moneys received for relief to Tsunami Victims for development of tourism facilities, such as those in Arugambe, Paanama, Kalpitiya etc. Health was privatized compelling people to pay unaffordable prices for their medicines, doctors and private hospitals. Flexible or free labour markets were proposed to allow already employed labour to be discharged with less compensation.

Similarly, education has been privatized compelling people to spend much more on private tuition, Private universities were proposed. Finally around 4 million children compete in education aiming for higher education opportunities, but many of them are dropped off half way. Out of over 250,000 students sitting for advanced level exams about 120,000 get sufficient marks to enter universities, but universities can admit only about 17,000 every year. So, over a hundred thousand students who are very intelligent and hard working are dropped off, no future plans. Worsening food situation will only increase the already too high a number of malnourished children and anemic mothers, thus preventing proper brain growth and physical growth of children destroying their future potential, the future of the whole nation.

Thus, we see that more manmade disasters add on to the natural disasters. The way agriculture is done today is another serious manmade disaster. We cut of trees and forests and reduce the effective use of sunlight that is absorbed by leaves of trees converting them into food for trees and for all living beings, this also worsens erosion that destroys the top soil that takes thousands of years to regenerate. We also add poisonous inputs such as chemical weedicides, pesticides and fertilizer, thereby weakening the ability of the soils to regenerate soil fertility through microbial activity; we kill insects and create much stronger and more resistant pests. All this destroys the natural process of sustainable and regenerative agriculture which is the only sure way of ensuring survival of life. Destroying natural agriculture is practiced as the main stream agriculture. Thus we prevent nature's free contribution to agriculture. This goes on all the time even at times when weather is good. This may be more destructive than the natural disasters that happen only from time to time. In doing this we also make the impact of natural disaster much worse. Fewer trees make the rain fall much more aggressive and erosion much more intense. Loss of top soil reduces the ability of soil to absorb and retain water making the droughts more frequent and losses more aggressive. Killing away microbes weakens the natural cycle and killing away insects weakens the natural pest control.

All this is known, but no serious attention is given by the policy makers and implementers to any of these. So, manmade disasters of all this type may be much more serious than the natural disasters.

If policy makers are unwilling to attend to these the people who are victims of these have to take it upon themselves to solve these. All these disasters are preventable.

How ?

People must begin to find their food from nature if they do not have enough money to buy them. Learn how nature gives free food. Protect and improve soil fertility by preventing erosion, begin with your small plot of land by building ridges, mulching and growing trees for soil fertility. Recycle all your organic matter, the leaves, branches and also animal dung and urine.

Maximize the absorption of sunlight by growing more trees to fill your land, growing trees to different canopies is the best way to maximize sunlight. This can also enhance your energy supply, fodder, timber and medicinal plants in addition to food.

Recycle all organic waste and organic matter after use. Save your natural seeds and set up plant nurseries to reduce the need to buy seeds and plants, Avoid using F-1 variety seeds because they cannot regenerate seeds. Use animal dung and urine to produce natural fertilizers and improve natural fertility.

Increase diversification of crops and use mix cropping to reduce pest attacks and improve natural control of pests. Improve food diversity and nutrition by growing a multiplicity of food crops, use the indigenous knowledge of use of medicinal plants to prevent ill health and cure diseases where possible.

Apply principles of agro forestry to improve forest cover and catchment areas.
Avoid using destructive, poisonous chemical inputs to prevent pollution of food, soil , water and environment.
organize marketing of products directly between communities of producers and communities of consumers, thereby reducing the losses made in trade through middlemen.
Teach children in schools, and at higher levels the principles of natural farming and the necessity of shifting to natural farming and to recover the ability of regeneration of nature and its resources.

Struggling to prevent destruction.

It is high time that we take up measures to protect scientific agriculture of the right type. Companies are given a free hand to propagate and market very destructive poisonous chemical pesticides, weedicides and fertilizers. They also freely market seeds that do not produce fertile seeds and are in the process of promoting genetically modified seeds and foods. All kinds of artificial foods that cause diseases such as diabetes, cancers and a host of other diseases are easily propagated, advertized and marketed. As explained already these are causing major disasters in the country. It has now become fairly clear that chemical fertilizers increase kidney diseases, chemically contaminated food reduces immunity in the body thus making more people susceptible to all kinds of diseases. All these are done with the blessings of people at the highest levels. They have also introduced certain types of ethics in the media that prevents direct reference to companies that cause these problems. Many such companies make use of Government departments to propagate their markets.

It is necessary for people to take up direct battles to prevent these disasters. Disaster risk reduction should include these too. There is a need for people's plans to introduce these remedies. Forth coming paradeshiya shaba elections is a good opportunity for people to work out their plans at local level and present their advantages and campaign for these. Funds allocated for village level programmes such as the "Api Wawamu Rata Nagamu", "Gama Neguma", "Gemi Diriya", "Maga Neguma" are more than enough to meet the requirements of the above disaster prevention plans at village level.

Such a strategy could harness the full creative potential of the people and the regenerative potential of nature. The slogan should be;

" Restore the ability of nature to regenerate itself and its resources".

This is a principle that should guide the future of the whole world. Nature has created all life , protected it and provided sustenance all this time. Now we have begun to destroy its ability to do so by destroying regenerative ability of nature. Now it's necessary that the whole of humanity must restore this ability for their own survival in the future

Sri Lanka has all the advantages of such a plan. We have good sunlight, good rain fall, good diversity of plants and bio diversity, very suitable geographical setting to develop natural irrigation systems, still remaining indigenous knowledge of natural agriculture and natural health ( ayurvedic medicine ), very high diversity of medicinal plants and food plants, Indigenous knowledge of cooking and preparation of herbal medicines. We also have a rich knowledge of working out agricultural technology utilizing nature's ways.

Indiginous philosophical resources

The Buddhist understanding of non attachment and non greed and the futility of accumulation of profits gives us very valuable guidelines to plan our ways of dealing with nature and dealing with other living beings. Combining these valuable resources of Buddhist Philosophy, indigenous natural farming and indigenous medicine is a valuable combination of resources that can guide us away from disasters.


Friday, January 14, 2011

Sri Lanka bans use of gunny bags in transportation of vegetables

(January 14, 2011) Sri Lanka Ministry of Cooperatives and Internal Trade has issued a gazette notification directing the transporters of vegetables to use plastic crates or any other proper method in transportation of vegetables.

The Ministry has given a grace period of one month to adjust to the new method. The Ministry Secretary Sunil Sirisena says that the offending transporters will be brought to book after this period. Consumer Affairs Authority has been assigned for the task, he says.

The Ministry says that improper practices used in transporting vegetables cause loss of produce. However, the traders say that the use of plastic crates cost space and the transport costs will go up since less amount of vegetables can be transported than in the loeeies filled in with gunny bags.




Thursday, January 13, 2011

Sri Lanka government to amend Irrigation Ordinance

(January 13, 2011) Sri Lanka Minister of Irrigation and Water Management Nimal Siripala de Silva says that the Irrigation Ordinance will be soon amended to enable to cope with the current and future needs.

A committee had been appointed to amend the Act and the amendments to the Ordinancet would be tabled in the parliament within the first quarter of the year, the Minister stated.

The Minister points out that the Ordinance has many inadequacies since for the 64 years since 1946, it has not undergone major amendments sans several slight amendments.

The committee appointed to amend the Ordinance has focussed to safety of the irrigation systems, protection of catchment areas, removal of squatters from catchment areas and prevention of water pollution.

He also said that public consultation would also be held in regard of amending the Irrigation Ordinance.



Wednesday, January 12, 2011

Right to one's Convictions Democratic Right to protest

To build a countervailing power of the people

A follow-up of the earlier discussion will take place on the 13th January 2011 at the Movement for National Land and Agricultural Reform (MONLAR), 1151/58,A , 4th Lane, Cotta Road, Rajagiriya at 4.00 p.m.

The action programme in relation to the attack on Dr. Vickramabahu Karunarathne at the Colombo International Airport, will be reviewed as the first item of the agenda.
Irrespective of bad weather, kindly attend this important discussion

In Solidarity,
Linus Jayatilake
President
United Federation of Labour (UFL)
Council Member of Monlar.


Saturday, January 8, 2011

Free Trade Zones in Ireland and Four Asian Countries | Trócaire

Trócaire

(At the beginning of the 1980s MONLAR undertook a study under the title “Export-Oriented Industrialization Strategy and the Free Trade Zones in Sri Lanka”. This was a joint study that was conducted in five countries on the same topic. They were Ireland, Philippines, Taiwan, Malaysia and Sri Lanka. This is the report of this study,)

In the 1950s, the world's first industrial free trade zone (FTZ), or export processing zone, (EPZ) was established at Shannon Airport. This experiment attracted a good deal of international interest and the results were regarded as a considerable success by UNIDO and other international agencies which urged developing countries to imitate the Shannon project. Since then some fifty countries have opened their own industrial FTZs and today well over one hundred of them ring the globe in Asia, Africa, and Latin America. In many less developed countries (LDCs) these zones are held to be a key element in their strategy for industrial and economic development.
This article very briefly presents some of the findings of a major research project on the economic and human consequences of FTZs in Taiwan, the Philippines, Malaysia, Sri Lanka and Ireland. The research was carried out in each country under the umbrella of the Asia Partnership for Human Development, a federation of twenty-one Roman Catholic development agencies from Asia, Europe, Australasia and North America. Trocaire took responsibility for the Irish study, A book containing the findings in considerably greater detail is due to be published shortly.1

The FTZ concept

Essentially, a free trade zone is an enclave within a country into which goods may be imported or from which they may be exported free of taxes, duties and often at least some of the regulations applying elsewhere in the country. Free ports or zones, for the purpose of facilitating trade, are by no means new, but the concept pioneered by Shannon was the development of an industrial estate within such a zone with factories and infrastructure provided for the convenience of the companies involved. Thus, even in a country which normally imposes substantial taxes or duties on imports or exports, as in Ireland in the 1950s or many developing countries today, it is possible for industrial firms within such a free trade enclave to import material inputs and capital equipment and to export their products freely. The main attraction of FTZs is thus for highly export-oriented firms which import many of their inputs.
Apart from the free trade aspect, other inducements to investment in FTZs often include profit tax concessions and government grants. In developing countries, further inducements include very low wages, waiving of health or safety regulations and limitations on workers' rights to organise unions. It is this latter aspect, concerning the conditions and rights of workers, that raises the question of social justice and the human consequences of FTZs, particularly since most of the companies operating in them are branches of wealthy multinational corporations producing goods for affluent markets and making profits for shareholders in those countries.

FTZs and industrialisation strategy

Most of the ex-colonies which gained independence in the twentieth century, including the five case studies referred to here, initially attempted to industrialise by import-substitution. Their first instinct was to erect protective barriers against imports behind which they hoped local industries would develop, sheltered from competition from advanced industrial countries. Ireland, which then had very little industry, adopted this strategy in the early 1930s, as did some of the major Latin American countries which were also independent at the time, and the real but limited gains which initially resulted made it seem an attractive approach in the post-War period for new states seeking an economic model. As they gained independence, Taiwan and Sri Lanka adopted protection in the late 1940s and the Philippines and Malaysia did so in the 1950s.
It gradually emerged, however, that there was an initial 'easy' phase of import-substitution during which growth occurred mainly in consumer goods industries with relatively low technological and skill requirements. Progressing further into more technologically demanding and skill-intensive industries, particularly in capital goods, proved to be slower and much more difficult. In addition, most of the protected industries which did develop remained uncompetitive in international terms so that Ireland, like the Latin American countries, still exported little of its industrial output by the 1950s. In these circumstances, stagnation eventually set in as the scope for 'easy' import- substitution was exhausted and export development failed to occur. By the early 1950s, as the new Asian states were moving into import-substitution, Ireland's industrialisation was already grinding to a halt. Taiwan made progress for a longer period, largely attributable to massive US aid amounting to over half of Taiwan's investment in the 1950s. But Sri Lanka, the Philippines and Malaysia experienced more or less chronic problems with the strategy after having some success in the initial 'easy' phase.
In response to the limitations of protectionist import-substitution, many developing countries, often under pressure from the IMF or World Bank, began to shift, to varying degrees, towards a more 'outward-looking' or export- oriented style of industrialisation. This change began in Ireland in the 1950s, followed later by Taiwan and then the Philippines, Malaysia and Sri Lanka. When implemented in its fullest sense, this strategy, which is now the strategy conventionally recommended by international bodies such as the World Bank, involves: (a) the dismantling of protection, moving to free international trade; (b) emphasis on export development rather than import substitution; and (c) an open door for investment by foreign multinational companies. In addition, although the state may offer general incentives such as investment grants and tax concessions, in the orthodox version of this strategy the state would rely on private enterprise and initiative rather than becoming actively involved in selecting particular industries for development and intervening directly to promote them.
Of the five countries, Ireland has adopted this strategy to the fullest extent since free trade with European countries was introduced under the Anglo-Irish Free Trade Agreement of 1965 and by accession to EEC membership in 1973. The other countries still retained elements of protection, although they were generally less restrictive than previously, but they have moved to attract foreign investment and to promote exports. In Taiwan, in particular, a further divergence from the orthodox approach is substantial direct state intervention to develop target industries, including considerable reliance on state enterprises in die modern large-scale sectors.2
Despite the variations in policy, all countries have a common programme to promote industrial exports and to attract investment by foreign multinational companies for that purpose. Industrial FTZs play a part in this effort by providing an attractive business environment free from the restrictions imposed by protection. Where protection is in operation, the zones are more attractive for many export-oriented firms than the rest of the country. The Shannon FTZ provided a unique environment within Ireland when it was established in the late 1950s, although the particular attraction of Shannon faded as Ireland's protection was dismantled, making the whole country akin to an FT2. Taiwan opened its first FTZ in 1966 and two more in the early 1970s. The other countries started later, with Malaysia opening ten zones between 1970 and 1977, while the Bataan zone in the Philippines began operations in 1972 with two more following in the late 1970s. Sri Lanka opened its first FTZ in 1978.

Economic impact of the FTZs

The experience of export-oriented industrialisation and FTZs in Ireland, Taiwan, Malaysia, the Philippines and Sri Lanka is very diverse, but at the same time the diversity suggests a general pattern of economic results. Ireland and Taiwan enjoyed certain advantages in attracting multinational firms which were probably not repeatable by most LDCs opening zones more recently, and accordingly they had more favourable results than the other three countries. At first, their advantage was partly just a matter of being among the first to actively seek out and offer incentives for foreign investment in export- oriented industries, so that they did not have to compete with a host of low- wage countries. Ireland could attract foreign firms offering wages and working conditions which were very good by LDC standards, and Taiwan was able to impose fairly stringent conditions on foreign investors, insisting on a minimum amount of value-added within the country.
Their "first-comer" advantage faded as time went on, but Ireland still had advantages over most low-wage LDCs in the form of political stability, a European location with guaranteed access to the UK market and later the EEC, relatively good infrastructure, skills and education, and a culture relatively familiar to American and European managers. So foreign firms paying high wages by LDC standards continued to invest in Ireland at a rate greatly disproportionate to the country's size. Taiwan, too, has had special advantages for attracting multinational firms, particularly in political stability (very different to Ireland in form, but still favourable to private capital) and a special strategic relationship with the USA which meant favoured access to US markets and a strong sense of security for investors.
For most LDCs without such special attractions the problem is that the available pool of mobile foreign investment is much too small to go round. If they are to get a significant share they are obliged to offer increasingly generous (and costly) incentives, to provide factories and infrastructure, perhaps to waive the application of laws and regulations, to keep labour costs very low and to provide a docile or repressed labour force. The economic consequences of this intense competition for foreign investment can be that there is little or no return on the host country's investment - the costs can be as great as the benefits. The social or human costs can also be substantial, a point discussed below.
To concentrate on the economic consequences of FTZs for the moment: a major aim of the zones was to boost exports and increase foreign exchange earnings. But rising exports would not in themselves represent significant economic progress if imports of material inputs were also rising rapidly, meaning that little of the value of production and export receipts was being retained in the host country. For the FTZs in the five countries, the net gain of exports over imports was as shown in Table 1.
Table 1
It can be seen that the net contribution of the zones to domestic production and foreign exchange earnings, after deducting the value of imported inputs, is far less than the value of exports, particularly in the three late comers - the Philippines, Sri Lanka and Malaysia. In these countries, not only are most material requirements imported, but value-added is also very low, meaning that the wealth created and retained in the country is only a small fraction of the value of total output.
A basic problem here is that the main way in which wealth is retained in the host country is through the payment of wages to the workforce since little of the material input requirements are sourced locally, government taxes on the firms involved are small or negligible and profits of the multinationals tend to be repatriated eventually. If wages have to be held at very low levels in order to attract the multinationals in the first place, their net contribution to the economy and foreign exchange earnings must be correspondingly small. The main reason why the proportion of wealth retained in the host country is so low in Malaysia, Sri Lanka and the Philippines, as compared with the higher levels in Taiwan and Ireland, is because wage levels are lower in the three latecomers than in Taiwan and much lower than in Ireland.
This problem raises a fundamental question about the FTZ policy in countries such as Malaysia, Sri Lanka and the Philippines which do not have the special attractions for multinationals of Ireland and Taiwan. Wages in such countries have to be held very low in order to attract foreign investment but low wages mean that there is relatively little benefit to the host country. So do the benefits justify the costs at all? In some cases at least, it seems they do not. A study of the Bataan FTZ in the Philippines concluded that, taking account of all benefits to the economy, there was a negative rate of return of-3 per cent a year on the government's investment in infrastructure and other costs. Net foreign exchange earnings of the zone were 85.5 million pesos in 1982, an insignificant amount for a project that had cost 3,790 million pesos in infrastructure, administrative costs and subsidies by that year.3 It remains to be seen whether this will also be the fate of the Sri Lankan and Malaysian zones but it seems possible (see Table 1).

Employment

Another major aim of the FTZs has been to create jobs, and employment figures for the zones in the five countries are shown in Table 2.
Table 2
Although the absolute employment figures may look substantial, they represent only small fractions of either the industrial or total workforce in each country. Nor does this understate the general importance of FTZs in developing countries since Taiwan has more employment in FTZs than any other country and Malaysia has the second highest number in the world. Thus, even in these countries, the employment impact is really quite small in relation to other industries or the total workforce, and it could not be regarded as a major contribution to industrial transformation. In addition, employment in FTZs in the five countries has been declining.
There are, of course, other export-oriented multinational companies outside the zones, particularly in Ireland where those outside Shannon are now far more important. But even taking account of all such foreign investment, the impact is still very small in relation to the size of the economy and labour force of these countries except in Ireland, and this is true of developing countries in general. There simply is not sufficient mobile foreign manufacturing investment available to bring about significant industrial development in most LDGs, so that relying on foreign firms for a major contribution to industrialisation is scarcely realistic for most of them.
Multinationals tend to have strong preferences for certain countries, depending on factors such as political "reliability", location and access to large markets, so that they are disproportionately concentrated in certain places. For example, about 80 per cent of the 450,000 jobs in Asia's FTZs in 1978 were in Taiwan, South Korea, Hong Kong and Singapore. The stock of US manufacturing investment in Ireland was equivalent to 5 per cent of that in all developing countries although Ireland's population amounted to only about 0.1 per cent of LDGs/ Where such a disproportionate concentration occurs in a very small country like Ireland or Singapore, there can be a significant impact on the economy, so that foreign-owned multinationals in Ireland, for example, now account for close to 40 per cent of manufacturing employment and about three-quarters of manufactured exports.
Such results must be regarded as exceptional and cannot justify the prevailing orthodox recommendation for LDCs in general of outward-looking policies, with a major role for multinational companies, nor the pressure imposed on many countries by the international financial organisations to adopt such policies.

Lessons for industrial strategy

To conclude on the economic aspects of the study, the five country case studies suggest a number of conclusions for industrial strategy in LDCs. First, as mentioned above, most countries cannot expect a really major contribution to overall economic growth and employment from foreign export-oriented industries. Special advantages in attracting foreign investment combined with a small size seem to be necessary for this to occur. In countries which do not seem particularly attractive to multinationals, there is a risk that any benefits from schemes to encourage their investment may notjustify the costs, and there are likely to be better ways for a government to invest its money.
Second, looking at Ireland, which went furthest in adopting the full free trade, free market approach, there seem to be serious risks in abandoning protection in a relatively weak late-developing economy. Ireland did experience fairly strong industrial growth under free trade in the 1960s and 1970s, but this was due to new foreign investment on a scale which most countries could not expect. Formerly protected, native Irish-owned firms lost ground steadily to competing imports once the dismantling of protection began, so that their employment stopped growing in the mid-1960s and Irish- owned firms now employ considerably less people than they did then. This is the experience of only one country, of course, but there are actually few examples of other late-industrialising countries with free trade policies from which to draw lessons, and the international trade performance of native- owned industries in these other countries, such as Singapore or Puerto Rico, does not inspire confidence.5
While protection alone may not provide a satisfactory solution to the problem of industrialisation in LDCs, the full free trade, free market approach is likely to be a very risky alternative for many of them.
Third, if LDCs are to industrialise successfully, most of them will have do so mainly by building up their own native-owned industries. Even in Ireland, where foreign multinationals have made proportionately the greatest contribution to industrialisation among the five countries, it has now been officially recognised in the White Paper on Industrial Policy (1984) that future progress must depend far more on native-owned industries, because competition for a declining volume of mobile (multinational) investment is constantly intensifying from both industrialised and developing countries.
Whereas Ireland has been presented at times as a model of one type of industrialisation strategy, depending on much foreign investment, it clearly does not have a great deal to teach the world about development of competitive native industries. Of the five countries, Taiwan has had most success in this area, with industrial growth rates among the highest in the world coming principally from native industries. Taiwan's strategy (as in South Korea, and Japan at an earlier stage) involved selecting priority or target industries for development, protecting them at first while actively nursing them to competitive maturity, and then breaking into export markets. More than just protection, it involved active and selective state intervention, with a good deal of direct state investment. There may be something to learn here.
Finally, it should be acknowledged that these conclusions are open to dispute, and many would not agree with them. But, at the least, it must also be admitted that the evidence in favour of the conventionally recommended outward-looking, free market strategy, relying heavily on foreign investment, is questionable and less than conclusive. In these circumstances, it is a matter of serious concern that international financial agencies should be pressing LDCs so hard to adopt such policies, often against the judgement of many people in the LDCs, so that, in the Philippines for example, major political crises have revolved around such issues of economic and industrial policy. Concern about this external pressure is increased by the fact that the agencies in question are controlled by the large developed countries, particularly the USA, whose major corporations have an obvious vested interest in opening up the LDCs for their activities.

Workers and their conditions

A full assessmentof the impact of FTZs should go beyond an economic analysis and look at the social impact, and accordingly the study of FTZs in live countries on which this article is based included surveys of workers in the zones. These surveys found major differences in the composition, conditions and attitudes of the zone workforce in Ireland, and to a lesser extent in Taiwan, compared with the other countries. Table 3 shows some basic data on the workers.
Table 3
A striking feature of the table is the extent to which the zone workforce in Malaysia, the Philippines and Sri Lanka is composed of young, single women from rural backgrounds, and in each of these countries this is quite different from the composition of the broader industrial labour force. Rates of pay are also very low, below the poverty line in Malaysia and the Philippines, and although official minimum wage rates are observed in Sri Lanka, wages there are even lower, the minimum rate being calculated as no more than enough to provide for a worker's most basic needs. In Taiwan, too, a very high proportion of the FTZ workforce are women, also younger and tending more to come from rural areas than in the rest of the country, although these aspects are less marked than in the other three countries. Wage rates in Taiwanese zones are considerably higher than in the other three Asian countries, but are nevertheless below the national average.
Only in Ireland does the general profile of the FTZ workforce correspond quite closely to that of the industrial sector in general, with wages and conditions also being comparable to the situation outside the zone, if not better in some respects. The survey of Shannon workers found most of them to be broadly satisfied with their employment, apart from a prevailing concern with long-term job security given the unemployment situation.
The situation of workers in the Asian zones is thus very different, and the country case studies suggest why this new proletariat of young, single, rural women has been particularly sought out by multinational companies there. Foreign firms investing in Ireland see a variety of attractions in doing so, especially ease of access to major European markets and, by comparison with alternative European locations, favourable tax concessions and grants, as well as relatively low wages by European standards. But they are not primarily attracted to Ireland by low labour costs and, indeed, if that was their main requirement they would go elsewhere in the world. Those investing in the Asian FTZs, on the other hand, are primarily seeking low-cost labour for unskilled labour-intensive production processes. Thus, they mostly employ young, single women because in each country their wage rates are lowest. Such workers are also considered more compliant, easier to discipline, more patient doing repetitive tasks and easier to dispose of than an older, predominantly male workforce, perhaps particularly with rural women who are new to industrial employment. In all respects labour costs are lowest with such workers.
The composition of the workforce in the Asian FTZs reflects the primary importance of the lowest possible labour costs in attracting foreign investment. Rising wages and agitation by workers for better conditions might scare away mobile multinational operations and so, in order to support an industrialisation strategy identified as central to economic growth, governments have acted to ensure that labour costs do not rise and workers do not challenge their employers. In the four Asian countries, zone workers were strongly discouraged or prohibited from forming workers' associations or joining unions, and this suppression or tight control of workers' organisations has in some cases carried over into general labour controls outside the zones.
Such suppression of workers' organisations is not peculiar to LDCs with an export-oriented strategy or FTZs. But there does seem to be a certain inexorable logic in it in such countries, given that the strategy depends quite fundamentally on offering cheap and tractable labour in order to attract highly mobile multinational companies which are free to choose from a wide range of possible locations. Governments in these countries are drawn into the paradoxical situation of suppressing groups of workers in their own population in the name of economic progress and development, despite the fact that the main benefit for their economies from foreign investment comes through the payment of wages. This situation results from the intensity of competition among so many LDCs in trying to attract foreign investment, so that the clearest beneficiaries are ultimately the multinational investors, and in some cases - indirectly - local employers.
The dissatisfaction of the workers themselves has been most evident in the Bataan FTZ in the Philippines where most of the workforce has unionised and strikes have occurred, despite the legal controls and deployment of the security forces within the zone. Even in Taiwan, where wage rates were much the highest of the four Asian countries, the researchers found evidence of considerable dissatisfaction. Although their survey collected generally positive responses to direct questions about working and living conditions in the zones, this could well be largely a reflection of the generally conformist and highly controlled cultural system. There was a high rate of employee turnover, with about 5 to 10 per cent of women workers quitting every month, while the young women employed in the zones commonly regard themselves as "students" temporarily employed to support their further education.
The Taiwanese study, in particular, exposed the psychological stress experienced by workers enclosed in an alien and unnatural environment. Indeed, the Asian studies in general highlighted the social and cultural dislocation experienced by young rural women drawn into this form of industrial employment. Living conditions, often in cramped dormitory accommodation, can be almost as stressful as working conditions.

Assessment

To conclude, how is one to assess the general benefit or value of foreign investment and the FTZ strategy in promoting the material and social welfare of the people in LDCs? One clear lesson from this set of comparative case studies is that the answer depends on a country's circumstances. The Irish case showed that the strategy can produce some quite positive results in a country with particular attractions for multinationals, even though this alone is insufficient to promote adequately the country's overall economic development. It is also clear, however, that in larger countries with no particularly strong attractions for foreign investors, the contribution of FTZs and 'multinational investment to economic development is very limited and may not even justify the costs to the government of the host country.
The pay, conditions and limitations of rights of workers in FTZs in such countries represent further objections to this strategy. It might be argued, however, that industrialisation is inevitably a painful process initially and that the workers of the Third World must endure social disruption and economic sacrifices similar to those borne by the working classes ofindustrialising Europe in the nineteenth century. In response to this, it is worth pointing out that Europe's industrialisation in the last century involved the accumulation of capital, skills and technology which eventually laid the foundations for far more prosperous societies. But in the Asian FTZs the unskilled, labour-intensive operations of foreign multinational companies, who develop and control the technology and receive the profits, promise no comparable long-term benefits for the host countries.
Furthermore, in retrospect, most Europeans would regard the conditions of workers in the early Industrial Revolution as deplorable and unjust, and there are similar grounds for concern now about the situation of many industrial workers in LDGs. It should be remembered that the exploitation of cheap labour convinced European workers of the need to organise and struggle for a more equitable place in their societies, and if that could be regarded as a legitimate objective the same applies now to those in the LDCs who are struggling for similar aims.
It might also be argued that the conditions of workers in the Asian FTZs at least represents an improvement on the rural poverty which is widespread in most of these countries, since the workers themselves have chosen to move from rural areas to work in the zones. This may be so, but rather than simply establishing that the FTZs represent real progress, it should draw attention to the causes of the apparently even more intolerable situation of many in the rural areas.
The Sri Lankan study looked at the conditions which pushed young rural women into the zone workforce, finding that the great majority of farm families work less than five acres, while there is considerable inequality in the pattern of land ownership.
The fact that zone workers might choose their employment in preference to living in conditions of deprivation in rural areas gives little cause to applaud the "progress" and opportunities presented by the FTZ. Real progress would be represented by reform in the rural areas so that people would not be attracted by such very low-paid employment. In Taiwan, for example, where a comprehensive land reform was carried out several decades ago, it is highly unlikely that people with an adequate living in rural areas would enter industrial employment for the sort of wages paid in the FTZs of the other three Asian countries.
Finally, it is evident from the five case studies that much of the exploitation of workers in the poorer countries results from competition between countries trying to attract a share of the relatively scarce amount of mobile multinational investment, and from competition between workers for the resulting employment. Competition and division between countries and workers keep wages very low and limit workers' freedoms. This is an international problem requiring an international response.
Footnotes
  1. Dennis Shoesmith (editor), Export Processing Zones in Five Countries: the Economic and Human Consequences,Asia Partnership for Human Development, Hong Kong (forthcoming). This article draws heavily on this study for information and some conclusions, summarising selected parts of it, although Dennis Shoesmith is not necessarily responsible for any views expressed here.
  2. See Robert Wade, "Dirigisme Taiwan-Style", IDS Bulletin, Sussex, Vol. 15, No. 2, April 1984.
  3. Peter G. Warr, "Export Promotion via Industrial Enclaves: The Philippines' Bataan Export Zone", Australian National University, 1984.
  4. Shoesmith, opcit., and US Department of Commerce, Survey of Current Business, October 1981.
  5. See Hock Beng Cheah, "Export-Oriented Industrialisation and Dependent Development: the Experience of Singapore", IDS Bulletin, Sussex, Vol, 12, No. 1, December 1980; and JoseJ. Villamil, "PuertoRico, 1948-1976-Tkt Limits of Dependent Growth", in Jose J. Villamil (editor), Transnational Capitalism and National Deoelopment Harvester Press, Hassocks, 1979.


Friday, January 7, 2011

Imported eggs in Sri Lanka's markets; local industry at peril

(January 07, 2010) Sri Lanka Minister of Cooperatives and Internal Trade Johnston Fernando says that a stock of three million eggs were to be cleared from the ports today and 70 million eggs have been ordered to control the escalating price of eggs at local markets.

He denied the allegations of the opposition and the local poultry associations that the imported eggs are not suitable for consumption.

Meanwhile, the Chairman of the All Lanka Poultry Industry Union Dr. D.D. Wanasinghe stated that the price of the locally produced eggs would go down by next week not because of the imports but the increase of production and decrease of demand.

He charged that the government measures to import eggs would affect the local poultry industry. He further accused that the Ministry of Veterinary Resources had not focussed attention to save the industry.


Twitter Delicious Facebook Digg Favorites More